TÍTULO: |
Ecological Economics
|
NÚMERO: |
Vol.63 No.1 15 June 2007
|
DIRECCIÓN ELECTRONICA: |
http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/journal/09218009
|
NOTAS: |
Este vínculo es el único para entrar a la base de datos Science Direct. Para ver el número de revista al que se hace referencia en este boletín, selecciónelo en el menú del lado izquierdo.
En este sitio usted encontrará la versión
íntegra de los artículos en formato HTML y Acrobat
(PDF).
|
|
|
ABSTRACTS |
Böhringer and Patrick E.P. Jochem. Measuring
the immeasurable — A survey of sustainability indices
|
Sustainability indices for countries provide a
one-dimensional metric to valuate country-specific information on
the three dimensions of sustainable development: economic, environmental,
and social conditions. At the policy level, they suggest an unambiguous
yardstick against which a country's development can be measured
and even a cross-country comparison can be performed. This article
reviews the explanatory power of various sustainability indices
applied in policy practice. We show that these indices fail to fulfill
fundamental scientific requirements making them rather useless if
not misleading with respect to policy advice.
|
Christian Rammel, Sigrid Stagl and Harald Wilfing. Managing
complex adaptive systems — A co-evolutionary perspective on
natural resource management
|
The overexploitation of natural resources and the
increasing number of social conflicts following from their unsustainable
use point to a wide gap between the objectives of sustainability
and current resource management practices. One of the reasons for
the difficulties to close this gap is that for evolving complex
systems like natural and socio-economic systems, sustainability
cannot be a static objective. Instead sustainable development is
an open evolutionary process of improving the management of social–ecological
systems, through better understanding and knowledge. Therefore,
natural resource management systems need to be able to deal with
different temporal, spatial and social scales, nested hierarchies,
irreducible uncertainty, multidimensional interactions and emergent
properties. The co-evolutionary perspective outlined in this paper
serves as heuristic device to map the interactions settled in the
networks between the resource base, social institutions and the
behaviour of individual actors. For this purpose we draw on ideas
from complex adaptive systems theory, evolutionary theory and evolutionary
economics. Finally, we outline a research agenda for a co-evolutionary
approach for natural resource management systems.
|
Diego Azqueta and Daniel Sotelsek. Valuing
nature: From environmental impacts to natural capital
|
Economic valuation of natural and environmental
assets is now a well established practice. Economic analysis provides
several methods for discovering the impact on social welfare associated
with changes in the ability of these assets to provide different
goods and services. In general terms, these valuation exercises
have been performed in the framework of Environmental Impact Assessment
or, more generally, Cost Benefit Analysis. There is, however, an
increasing demand nowadays to go beyond this framework and to value
natural capital (natural resource stocks, land and ecosystems) as
such. There are two main reasons for this new demand. On the one
hand, sustainability requires that proper account should be taken
of capital depreciation and, therefore, there is a need to value
natural capital changes. This valuation process, nevertheless, only
makes sense when some kind of substitution between natural and other
forms of capital is allowed. On the other hand, there is also an
increasing tendency to demand that the stock of natural capital
present in a given territory be valued, either to discover one of
the main components of social wealth or to help adequately plan
changes in land use. Yet, whereas conventional valuation methods
are probably adequate to fulfill the first task, this is less true
in the case of the second, while even more difficulties arise in
connection with the third one. Even if at first sight the process
appears conceptually identical, these tasks are of a different order
of magnitude, as the experience of both the World Bank and the Statistics
Division of the United Nations in this respect clearly shows.
|
Randall Bluffstone. Privatization and
contaminated site remediation in Central and Eastern Europe: Do
environmental liability policies matter?
|
This paper examines the effects on site remediation
decisions after state-owned firms have been privatized of providing
environmental information to potential investors and undertaking
site remediation planning prior to privatization. The literature
suggests that to minimize distortions created by uncertain environmental
problems, governments should invest in environmental information
for potential investors, inventory problems and develop plans for
remediation. One of the believed benefits is a higher probability
of site remediation, because with uncertainty resolved potential
conflicts after privatization are less likely. Few countries in
Central Europe, which has experienced both environmental problems
and privatization on enormous scales, have adopted this advice.
Using firm-level data, empirical analysis is presented, which suggests
providing only information to investors is insufficient to spur
remediation. Inventorying site contamination and planning remediation
prior to privatization is a much more effective measure. Combining
provision of information with remediation planning is found to be
the most powerful policy package for encouraging remediation.
|
Dominic Moran, Alistair McVittie, David J. Allcroft
and David A. Elston. Quantifying public preferences
for agri-environmental policy in Scotland: A comparison of methods
|
his paper compares two methods for determining
policy priorities for reform of Scottish agricultural support. Multifunctional
agriculture attempts to establish a new balance between traditional
commodity support and payment for the production of non-market goods
and services that are increasingly demanded by the public. Supplying
non-market goods presents particular problems for optimal policy
design, not least the elicitation of consumer demand for those goods.
From public focus groups, a range of attributes was derived as central
to the Scottish public’s preferences for future agri-environmental
reform. This information was then combined in two separate survey
methods using the Analytical Hierarchy Process (AHP) and choice
experiments (CE). Both applications suggest that the public has
defined preferences and a willingness to pay (using general income
taxation) to affect changes beyond the status quo, and that policy
payments should be targeted towards both environmental and social
benefits. The divergent preference orderings derived from the alternative
methods can be considered in the light of previous methodological
debates on question framing, bounded rationality and respondent
uncertainty. We speculate about the validity of alternative methodologies
for informing particular policy questions.
|
Neha Khanna and Florenz Plassmann. Total
factor productivity and the Environmental Kuznets Curve: A comment
and some intuition
|
Chimeli and Braden [Chimeli, Ariaster B., Braden,
John B., 2005. Total factor productivity and the Environmental Kuznets
Curve. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 49, 366–380]
derive a necessary and sufficient condition under which inter-country
differences in total factor productivity can yield an Environmental
Kuznets Curve. They argue that their results emphasize the importance
of differences in total factor productivity across countries as
well as the need for decreasing returns to scale in pollution-abating
technologies for the existence of an Environmental Kuznets Curve.
We show that their Proposition 1 is equivalent to Proposition 2
in Lieb [Lieb, Christoph M., 2002. The Environmental Kuznets Curve
and satiation: a simple static model. Environment and Development
Economics 7, 429–448]. This implies that, even in Chimeli
and Braden's model, contemporaneous changes in the marginal rate
of substitution between environmental quality and consumption on
the demand side and the marginal rate of transformation between
these goods on the supply side drive the pollution–income
relationship. This is a very general condition that does not rely
on either differences in total factor productivity or decreasing
returns to scale in abatement, and which is widely applicable.
|
Karl W. Steininger, Birgit Friedl and Brigitte Gebetsroith.
Sustainability impacts of car road pricing: A computable general
equilibrium analysis for Austria
|
Nationwide car road pricing schemes are discussed
across Europe. We analyse the impacts of such schemes with respect
to environmental, economic and social indicators of sustainability,
also quantifying the trade-offs among these three dimensions under
different charging principles and revenue recycling options. In
our analysis we employ a computable general equilibrium (CGE) approach,
develop a modelling structure for private transport and provide
detailed empirical analysis for the case of Austria. Regarding the
social dimension, it has often been argued that poorer households
(and commuters) would have to bear a disproportionate share of the
road pricing burden. We find the contrary, i.e. a stronger negative
policy impact on richer households, and on a small group of intensive
car users. The choice of revenue recycling is able to ameliorate
the negative social and economic effects of road pricing, without
reversing the desired positive environmental effects. For political
feasibility, questions of distributional impacts are most urgent
and therefore we address them systematically within a quantitative
framework.
|
Carlos José Caetano Bacha and Luiz Carlos Estraviz
Rodriguez. Profitability and social impacts of reduced
impact logging in the Tapajós National Forest, Brazil —
A case study
|
Brazil contains the world's largest tropical rainforests,
most located in the Amazon River Basin. Over the last three decades,
rapid growth of this region's deforested area has had negative impacts.
To minimize these impacts and maintain biodiversity, the Brazilian
Government has established several national forests in the Basin.
The ITTO Project, a reduced impact logging (RIL) operation, was
recently carried out at one of these forests: the Tapajós
National Forest, also known as Flona Tapajós. This paper
evaluates the Project's profitability and its effect on local residents.
The Project, which ran between 1999 and 2003, was coordinated by
the Brazilian Institute of Environment and Renewable Natural Resources
(IBAMA), with funding for planning and monitoring provided by the
United Kingdom's Department of International Development (DFID)
working through and approved by the International Tropical Timber
Organization (ITTO). Treviso Agropecuária Ltda, a private
logging company, carried out timber extraction on the Project site.
Our evaluation found the ITTO Project to have been highly profitable
for Treviso, even after their compliance with all Brazilian labor
and environmental laws. This finding was based on field interviews
and the examination of documents from IBAMA and Treviso. Treviso's
mean internal rate of return from the Project was calculated to
have been 35.79%, considerably higher than that generated by the
region's farms and ranches. The ITTO Project positively impacted
Project workers, providing employment and exposing them to rainforest
management techniques that maximize timber production while minimizing
forest destruction. The paper closes by suggesting that more of
the direct and indirect benefits of new reduced impact logging projects
on Brazilian national forest land need to be channeled to the local
population to increase the probability of them act as capable forest
custodians.
|
Pia Bøgelund. Making green discourses
matter in policy-making: Learning from discursive power struggles
within the policy area of car taxation
|
This paper is about stability and change in the
policy-making discourse of a traditional neoclassical policy area,
the area of car taxation. Stability is here related to the unquestioned
continuation of a traditional neoclassical economics perspective
in policy-making, whereas change is related to the introduction
and impact of environmental concerns. The aim of the paper is to
investigate, what makes green discourses matter in traditional policy-making.
It is based on an in-depth study of policy-making processes related
to car taxation in two environmental front-runner countries, Sweden
and Denmark.
Making green discourses matter in policy-making
is an important contemporary environmental challenge. Therefore,
as Tian Shi argues, we need more research into the institutional
setting of the policy-making process. Ecological economics as a
policy science has to have a broad understanding of the political
economic nature of the policy process. Taking this standpoint as
the point of departure, the paper seeks to uncover questions such
as, what is the policy-making reality in which Swedish and Danish
green discourses have to make a difference? How do existing neoclassical
regimes react, when green actors attempt to influence policy-making
from an environmental point of view? And to what extent can green
discourses actually have an impact on the policy world within the
area of car taxation?
The paper concludes that the traditional neoclassical
economic discourse is particularly robust and resistant against
alternative green discourses. Stability rather than change is the
dominating picture. This does not imply that environmental concerns
will not be taken into account in the future. Rather it implies
that only the changes, which keep up the existing order, or enhance
the narrow power-related interests of the dominating actors, will
materialise more or less easily. The rest is a power struggle in
which timing, coalition-building, persistence and thorough knowledge
about the field in question is of importance. In this struggle change
agents will also benefit from the ability to rethink dominating
ways of thinking and doing in an environmentally benign way. A rethinking
that is based on environmental values while at the same time holding
positive visions that are ‘compatible’ with the existing
dominating discourse.
|
Jouni Paavola. Institutions and environmental
governance: A reconceptualization
|
This article presents the conceptual revisions
needed to extend the new institutional approach to environmental
governance from its current local and international domains of application
to all governance solutions, including national environmental and
natural resource use policies and multi-level governance solutions
that are increasingly used to address global environmental change.
The article suggests that environmental governance is best understood
as the establishment, reaffirmation or change of institutions to
resolve conflicts over environmental resources. It also explains
why the choice of these institutions is a matter of social justice
rather than of efficiency. The article suggests a way to understand
formal and state-centered governance solutions as forms of collective
ownership not unlike common property. The article demonstrates how
institutional analysis can gain resolution by looking at the functional
and structural tiers, organization of governance functions, and
formulation of key institutional rules as key aspects of the design
of governance institutions.
|
Alexey Voinov and Joshua Farley. Reconciling
sustainability, systems theory and discounting
ages
|
Most definitions of sustainability imply that a
system is to be maintained at a certain level, held within certain
limits, into the indefinite future. Sustainability denies run-away
growth, but it also avoids any decline or destruction. This sustainability
path is hard to reconcile with the renewal cycle that can be observed
in many natural systems developing according to their intrinsic
mechanisms and in social systems responding to internal and external
pressures. Systems are parts of hierarchies where systems of higher
levels are made up of subsystems from lower levels. Renewal in components
is an important factor of adaptation and evolution. If a system
is sustained for too long, it borrows from the sustainability of
a supersystem and rests upon lack of sustainability in subsystems.
Therefore by sustaining certain systems beyond their renewal cycle,
we decrease the sustainability of larger, higher-level systems.
For example, Schumpeter's theory of creative destruction posits
that in a capitalist economy, the collapse and renewal of firms
and industries is necessary to sustain the vitality of the larger
economic system. However, if the capitalist economic system relies
on endless growth, then sustaining it for too long will inevitably
borrow from the sustainability of the global ecosystem. This could
prove catastrophic for humans and other species. To reconcile sustainability
with hierarchy theory, we must decide which hierarchical level in
a system we want to sustain indefinitely, and accept that lower
level subsystems must have shorter life spans. In economic analysis,
inter-temporal discount rates essentially tell us how long we should
care about sustaining any given system. Economists distinguish between
discount rates for individuals based on personal time preference,
lower discount rates for firms based on the opportunity cost of
capital, and even lower discount rates for society. For issues affecting
even higher-level systems, such as global climate change, many economists
question the suitability of discounting future values at all. We
argue that to reconcile sustainability with inter-temporal discounting,
discount rates should be determined by the hierarchical level of
the system being analyzed.
|
Xuehong Wang, Jeff Bennett, Chen Xie, Zhitao Zhang
and Dan Liang. Estimating non-market environmental benefits
of the Conversion of Cropland to Forest and Grassland Program: A
choice modeling approach
|
The non-market values of the environmental benefits
derived from the Conversion of Cropland to Forest and Grassland
Program (also known as the Grain for Green Program and the Sloped
Land Conversion Program) in the Loess Plateau region of North West
China were estimated using choice modeling both on-site in Xi'an
and Ansai and off-site in Beijing. Separate choice models were estimated
for the three sites and the results compared. Significant differences
were found between the implicit price estimates derived from the
multinomial logit (MNL) model and the random parameter logit (RPL)
model for some environmental attributes. Based on the results from
the RPL models, the average willingness to pay per respondent household
in Beijing was CNY882.56 (USD109.44) each year for the environmental
improvements on the Loess Plateau provided by the Program, a payment
level significantly higher than the comparable estimates of CNY342.56
(USD42.48) in Xi'an and CNY388.08 (USD48.12) in Ansai.
|
Minna Halme, Markku Anttonen, Mika Kuisma, Nea Kontoniemi
and Erja Heino. Business models for material efficiency
services: Conceptualization and application
|
Despite the abundant research on material flows
and the growing recognition of the need to dematerialize the economy,
business enterprises are still not making the best possible use
of the many opportunities for material efficiency improvements.
This article proposes one possible solution: material efficiency
services provided by outside suppliers. It also introduces a conceptual
framework for the analysis of different business models for eco-efficient
services and applies the framework to material efficiency services.
Four business models are outlined and their feasibility is studied
from an empirical vantage point. In contrast to much of the previous
research, special emphasis is laid on the financial aspects. It
appears that the most promising business models are ‘material
efficiency as additional service’ and ‘material flow
management service’. Depending on the business model, prominent
material efficiency service providers differ from large companies
that offer multiple products and/or services to smaller, specialized
providers. Potential clients (users) typically lack the resources
(expertise, management's time or initial funds) to conduct material
efficiency improvements themselves. Customers are more likely to
use material efficiency services that relate to support materials
or side-streams rather than those that are at the core of production.
Potential client organizations with a strategy of outsourcing support
activities and with experience of outsourcing are more keen to use
material efficiency services.
|
Giuseppe Di Vita. Exhaustible resources
and secondary materials: A macroeconomic analysis
|
In this paper we have developed an endogenous growth
model to deal with exhaustible resources and secondary materials
together, under the assumptions that these two inputs are, or are
not, technologically perfect substitutes of each other, in order
to compare the results obtained under both hypotheses. We highlight
the implication of these two assumptions on the rate of growth of
total output and upon the flow of exhaustible resources extracted.
There are also some other interesting findings related to the spill-over
on welfare of the waste recycling process, and the dynamics of shadow
prices of both inputs considered. Finally, some implications on
Hotelling's rule also emerge in our analytical framework.
|
Jeffrey A. Michael.Episodic flooding
and the cost of sea-level rise
|
Previous studies of the cost of sea-level rise
focus on the economic loss to inundated property rather than increased
damage from episodic flood events to non-inundated property above
sea level. This study uses a unique GIS database of three geographically
diverse Chesapeake Bay communities that includes 1-ft elevation
contours from remote sensing data, local tax assessment records,
and aerial photographs of property location. Hedonic property value
models estimate the loss from complete inundation, closely following
the methodology of previous studies. Increased damage from episodic
flooding is estimated using elevation-rated, actuarially fair flood
insurance rates. Using a 3-ft sea-level rise over 100 years scenario,
damage from episodic flooding averages 9 times the estimated loss
from complete inundation, and is an average of 28 times greater
under a 2-ft sea-level rise scenario. Although the study areas are
not representative of all coastal areas, the results suggest that
current studies may substantially underestimate the cost of sea-level
rise.
|
Sugata Marjit, Saibal Kar and Hamid Beladi. Protectionary
bias in agriculture: A pure economic argument
|
Empirical evidence suggests that the agricultural
sector in the developed countries has enjoyed a greater degree of
protection than the import-competing manufacturing sectors. Usually
this is attributed to strong farm lobbies and hence on political
factors. We provide a theoretical model and a possible explanation
of this phenomenon based on purely economic arguments. Two importables
are accommodated in a three-good three-factor model of trade and
production, one is a labor-intensive manufacturing good and the
other is an agricultural commodity. This captures the trade pattern
of a typical industrialized country with an agricultural sector
such as Europe and the USA. We show that uniform tariffs in agriculture
and labor-intensive manufacturing will definitely hurt the land
owners in real terms and may reduce their absolute return. Hence,
if there has to be protection, it has to be biased in favor of agriculture.
|
Arno J. van der Vlist, Cees Withagen and Henk Folmer.Technical
efficiency under alternative environmental regulatory regimes: The
case of Dutch horticulture
|
We consider the performance of small and medium
sized enterprises in Dutch horticulture under different environmental
policy regimes across time. We address the question whether technical
performance differs under these alternative regulatory regimes to
test Porter's hypothesis that stricter environmental regulation
reduces technical inefficiency. For this purpose, we use a stochastic
production frontier framework allowing for inclusion of policy variables
to measure the effect of alternative environmental policy regimes
on firms' performance. The main result is that stricter environmental
policy regimes have indeed reduced technical inefficiencies in Dutch
horticulture. The estimation results indicate amongst others that
the 1997 agreement on energy, nutrient and pesticides use enhances
technical efficiency. Firms under the strict environmental policy
regime are found to be more technically efficient than those under
a lax regime, thereby supporting the claims by Porter and Van der
Linde (Porter, M., Van der Linde, C., 1995. Green and Competitive:
Ending the stalemate. Harvard Business Review 73, pp. 120–137)
concerning Dutch horticulture.
|
Jesus Ramos-Martin, Mario Giampietro and Kozo Mayumi.On
China's exosomatic energy metabolism: An application of multi-scale
integrated analysis of societal metabolism (MSIASM)
|
The methodology of multi-scale integrated analysis
of societal metabolism (MSIASM) is applied to the analysis of the
recent evolution of Chinese economy. This paper has two goals: (1)
to show the MSIASM scheme is effective in handling in an integrated
way different types of data, mixing extensive and intensive variables,
on different levels; and (2) to provide a multi-scale integrated
analysis of the trajectory of development of China. The quality
of possible scenarios is checked by identifying constraints affecting
their feasibility and by characterizing them in relation to different
dimensions and scales of analysis.
This entails 4 tasks: (i) identifying a set of
benchmarks that makes it possible to compare different characteristics
and features of China to other countries and to the average values
calculated for the world level; (ii) explaining the differences
found over the selected set of benchmarks, by looking at the characteristics
of the various sub-sectors of Chinese economy; (iii) understanding
existing trends and future feasible paths of China's development
by studying the existence of reciprocal constraints between the
whole economy and its compartments; and (iv) examining possible
future scenarios of development for China.
|
Bernd Meyer, Martin Distelkamp and Marc Ingo Wolter.Material
efficiency and economic-environmental sustainability. Results of
simulations for Germany with the model PANTA RHEI
|
Based on empirical evidence, the paper discusses
the impact of a consulting and information program for the improvement
of material productivity with regard to economic and environmental
targets for Germany. The instrument used in the analysis is the
integrated economic-environmental model PANTA RHEI, which is parameterized
econometrically. The paper presents the model and shows in a baseline
forecast that without policy changes, sustainability will be violated
in both the economic and the environmental dimensions. This applies
to the latter particularly with regard to land use and material
consumption. The alternative simulation that introduces a consulting
and information program for the improvement of material productivity
yields a win–win result: growth rates of GDP and employment
are rising, the public debt is reduced, and material consumption
is much lower than in the baseline and remains at the actual level,
which means that a decoupling of growth and material consumption
is possible.
|
Esther Velázquez.Water trade in
Andalusia. Virtual water: An alternative way to manage water use
|
The main idea of this paper is to analyse the relationships
between the productive process and the commercial trade with water
resources used by them. For that, the first goal is to find out,
by means of the estimation of virtual water, the exported crops
which have the highest water consumption. Similarly, we analyse
the crops that are imported and therefore, might contribute to save
water. The second objective is to put forward new ways to save water
by means of the virtual water trade.
This first conclusion contradicts not only the
comparative advantages theory but also the environmental sustainability
logic. The previous conclusion is derived from the great exports
of water via potatoes and vegetables, and also via citrus fruit
and orchards; and, on the other hand, from the imports, such as
cereals and arable crops, with lower water requirements. The second
conclusion affirms as Andalusia utilises large amounts of water
in its exports, and in turn, it does not produce goods with low
water requirements, the potential saving would be very significant
if the terms of our trade were the other way round. We are convinced
that the agricultural sector must modify the use of water to a great
extent in order to reach significant water savings and an environmental
sustainability path.
|
Luke M. Brander, Pieter Van Beukering and Herman S.J.
Cesar.The recreational value of coral reefs: A meta-analysis
|
Coral reefs are highly productive ecosystems that
provide a variety of valuable goods and services, including recreational
opportunities. The open-access nature and public good characteristics
of coral reefs often result in them being undervalued in decision
making related to their use and conservation. In response to this,
there now exists a substantial economic valuation literature on
coral reefs. For the purposes of conducting a meta-analysis of this
literature, we collected 166 coral reef valuation studies, 52 of
which provided sufficient information for a statistical meta-analysis,
yielding 100 separate value observations in total. Focusing on recreational
values, we use US$ per visit as the dependent variable in our meta-analysis.
The meta-regression results reveal a number of important factors
in explaining variation in coral reef recreational values, notably
the area of dive sites and the number of visitors. Different valuation
methods are shown to produce widely different values, with the contingent
valuation method producing significantly lower value estimates.
Using a multi-level modelling approach we also control for authorship
effects, which proves to be highly significant in explaining variation
in value estimates. We assess the prospects for using this analysis
for out-of-sample value transfer, and find average transfer errors
of 186%. We conclude that there is a need for further high-quality
valuation research on coral reefs.
|
Yoh Iwasa, Tomoe Uchida and Hiroyuki Yokomizo.Nonlinear
behavior of the socio-economic dynamics for lake eutrophication
control
|
To succeed in combating lake eutrophication, cooperation
of local inhabitants, small factories, and farmers in reducing phosphorus
discharge is very important. But the willingness of each player
to cooperate would depend on the cooperation of other players and
on the level of environmental concern of the society in general.
Here we study the integrated dynamics of people's choice of behavior
and the magnitude of eutrophication. Assumptions are: there are
a number of players who choose between alternative options: a cooperative
and environment-oriented option is more costly than the other. The
decision of each player is affected by “social pressure”
as well as by economical cost of the options. The lake pollution
increases with the total phosphorus released, and a high pollution
level in the lake would enhance the social pressure. The model includes
a positive and a negative feedback loops which create diverse dynamical
behavior. The model often shows bistability — having an equilibrium
with a high level of cooperation among people and clean water, and
the other equilibrium with low cooperation and polluted water, which
are simultaneously stable. The model also shows fluctuation between
a high and a low levels of cooperation in alternating years, cycle
with a longer periodicity, or chaotic fluctuation. Conservatism
of people stabilizes the system and sometimes helps maintaining
cooperation. The system may show unexpected parameter dependence
— the improved phosphorus removing efficiency might make water
more polluted if it causes the decline in the environmental concern
and cooperation among people.
|
Jordi Roca and Mònica Serrano.Income
growth and atmospheric pollution in Spain: An input–output
approach
|
The relationships between economic growth and environmental
pressures are complex. Since the early nineties, the debate on these
relationships has been strongly influenced by the Environmental
Kuznets Curve hypothesis, which states that during the first stage
of economic development environmental pressures increase as per
capita income increases, but once a critical turning point has been
reached these pressures diminish as income levels continue to increase.
However, to date such a delinking between economic growth and emission
levels has not happened for most atmospheric pollutants in Spain.
The aim of this paper is to analyse the relationship between income
growth and nine atmospheric pollutants in Spain. In order to obtain
empirical outcomes for this analysis, we adopt an input–output
approach and use NAMEA data for the nine pollutants. First, we undertake
a structural decomposition analysis for the period 1995–2000
to estimate the contribution of various factors to changes in the
levels of atmospheric emissions. And second, we estimate the emissions
associated with the consumption patterns of different groups of
households classified according to their level of expenditure.
|
Kristin Shrader-Frechette.
Power, justice,
and the environment: A critical appraisal of the environmental justice
movement, ed. by David Naguib Pellow and Robert J. Brulle, MIT Press,
2005. ISBN 0-262-66193-5
|
No tiene resumen
|
Joseph Romm, Editor, The Hype About Hydrogen:
Fact and Fiction in the Race to Save the Climate.
Island Press (2004) ISBN 155963703X 240 pp.
|
No tiene resumen
|
Edward Barbier, Editor, Natural Resources
and Economic Development, Cambridge University Press (2006)
426 pp., ISBN: 9780521823135.
Kevin P. Gallagher
|
No tiene resumen
|
Edward Elgar and OECD, Cheltenham, U.K. The
distributional effects of environmental policy, Yse Serret and Nick
Johnstone, eds., Northampton MA, 2006. ISBN: 1845423151, x + 323
pp
|
No tiene resumen
|
|
TÍTULO: |
European Economic Review
|
NÚMERO: |
Vol.51 No.4 May 2007
|
DIRECCIÓN ELECTRONICA: |
http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/journal/00142921
|
NOTAS: |
Este vínculo es el único para entrar a la base de datos Science Direct. Para ver el número de revista al que se hace referencia en este boletín, selecciónelo en el menú del lado izquierdo.
En este sitio usted encontrará la versión íntegra de los artículos en formato Acrobat (PDF).
|
|
|
ABSTRACTS |
Editorial Board
Page IFC
PDF (76 K)
|
No tiene resumen
|
Eckhard Janeba.International trade and
consumption network externalities
|
This paper studies the effects of trade liberalization
in the presence of consumption network externalities. The framework
is applicable to the choice of network products and sheds light
on the debate on globalization and culture. In an extended Ricardian
model of international trade the paper shows that: (i) trade is
not Pareto inferior to autarky if the free trade equilibrium is
unique; (ii) trade is not Pareto superior to autarky if both countries
are diverse (network competition) under free trade, but can be if
each country is homogenous (network monopoly); (iii) and when multiple
free trade equilibria exist everybody in a country can lose from
free trade if that country is homogenous under autarky. Consumers
of imported network goods tend to gain, while consumers of exported
network goods tend to lose from trade liberalization.
|
Adriaan Kalwij and Arjan Verschoor.Not
by growth alone: The role of the distribution of income in regional
diversity in poverty reduction
|
This study examines the role of the distribution
of income in determining the responsiveness of poverty to income
growth and changes in income inequality using panel data of 58 developing
countries for the period 1980–1998. We show that the large
cross-regional variation in the capacity of income growth to reduce
poverty, i.e. the income elasticity, is largely explained by differences
in the initial distribution of income and present region and time
specific estimates of the income and Gini elasticities of poverty.
We find that the income elasticity of poverty in the mid-1990s equals
-1.31 on average and ranges from -0.71 for Sub-Saharan Africa to
-2.27 for the Middle East and North Africa, and that the Gini elasticity
of poverty equals 0.80 on average and ranges from 0.01 in South
Asia to 1.73 in Latin America. Furthermore we show that while differing
income growth rates account for most of the regional diversity in
poverty trends, the additional impact of differences across regions
in rates of inequality change and income and inequality elasticities
of poverty is almost always significant and far too large to be
ignored, most notably so in Eastern Europe and Central Asia.
|
Hiau Looi Kee and Bernard Hoekman.Imports,
entry and competition law as market disciplines
|
Numerous countries have adopted or strengthened
competition laws in the past two decades. At the same time, domestic
industries in most countries are facing ever more intense pressure
from imports. In this paper we study the impact of competition law
on domestic competition for a large number of countries over time,
controlling for the presence of imports and the number of domestic
firms. We find that while industries that have higher import exposure
or larger numbers of domestic firms tend to be more competitive,
the direct effect of competition law on competition is insignificant.
However, we also find that industries that operate under a competition
law tend to have a larger number of domestic firms. This suggests
that competition laws may have an indirect effect on domestic competition
by promoting entry.
|
Patrick W. Schmit.Optimal selling strategies
when buyers may have hard information
|
Consider a revenue-maximizing seller who can sell
an object to one of n potential buyers. Each buyer either has hard
information about his valuation (i.e., evidence that cannot be forged)
or is ignorant. The optimal mechanism is characterized. It turns
out that more ignorance can increase the expected total surplus.
Even when the buyers are ex ante symmetric, the object may be sold
to a buyer who does not have the largest willingness-to-pay. Nevertheless,
an additional buyer increases the expected total surplus in the
symmetric case, whereas more competition can be harmful if there
are ex ante asymmetries.
|
Arno Riedl and Frans van Winden.An experimental
investigation of wage taxation and unemployment in closed and open
economies
|
We investigate experimentally the economic effects
of wage taxation to finance unemployment benefits for a closed economy
and an international economy. The main findings are the following.
(i) There is clear evidence of a vicious circle in the dynamic interaction
between the wage tax and unemployment. (ii) Employment is boosted
by budget deficits but subsequent tax rate adjustments to balance
the budget lead to employment levels substantially lower than theoretically
predicted. (iii) A sales risk for producers due to price uncertainty
on output markets appears to cause a downward pressure on factor
employment. For labor the wage tax exacerbates this adverse effect.
|
Mark Melatos and Alan Woodland. Endogenous
trade bloc formation in an asymmetric world
|
This paper investigates how variations in endowments
and the structure of preferences impact on the coalition formation
decisions of asymmetric countries. There exist relatively few general
results on the relationship between country characteristics and
trade bloc formation. Here, new light is shed on this issue by systematically
simulating bloc formation and by explicitly analysing the blocking
behaviour of coalitions. A general equilibrium model of world trade
is implemented with equilibrium coalition formation being modelled
using the equilibrium concept of the core. It is found that global
free trade is observed when all countries are similar. Customs unions
tend to form between countries with ‘adjacent’ consumer
preferences or with ‘adjacent’ endowments of their export
commodity. Finally, in contrast to the existing literature but consistent
with observed behaviour, it is found that free trade areas often
Pareto dominate customs unions, provided consumer preferences differ
sufficiently.
|
Silja Göhlmann and Roland Vaubel. The
educational and occupational background of central bankers and its
effect on inflation: An empirical analysis
|
We test the hypothesis that the inflation preferences
of central bankers depend on their educational and/or occupational
background. In a panel data analysis for the euro area and eleven
countries since 1973, we explain inflation either by the weights
with which the educational and occupational characteristics of the
391 council members were represented in the various central bank
councils or by the education or occupation of the median council
members. Control variables are added. Our most robust result is
that former members of the central bank staff prefer significantly
lower inflation rates than former politicians do.
|
Mattias Ganslandt and Keith E. Maskus. Vertical
distribution, parallel trade, and price divergence in integrated
markets
|
We develop a model of vertical pricing in which
an original manufacturer sets wholesale prices in two markets that
are integrated at the distributor level by parallel imports (PI).
The manufacturing firm needs to set these two prices to balance
three competing interests: restricting competition in the PI-recipient
market, avoiding resource wastes due to actual trade, and reducing
the double-markup problem in the PI-source nation. These tradeoffs
imply the counterintuitive result that retail prices could diverge
as a result of declining trading costs, even as the volume of PI
increases. Thus, in some circumstances it may be misleading to think
that permitting PI is an unambiguous force for price integration.
|
Jacques Melitz. North, South and distance
in the gravity model
|
t is generally assumed that distance in the gravity
model strictly reflects frictions impeding bilateral trade. However,
distances North–South could also reflect differences in factor
endowment that provide opportunities for profitable trade. This
paper investigates the hypothesis that if we control for distance
in the ordinary sense, differences North–South promote international
trade. The hypothesis receives ample support. Moreover, the significance
of differences North–South survives a battery of robustness
tests, concerning period, distinctions between differences in latitude
North–North, North–South and South–South, and
controls for other measures of differences in factor endowment,
such as differences in per capita output and differences in average
temperature, rainfall, and seasonal range in temperature. The impact
of differences North–South on bilateral trade has also been
falling. This decline, in turn, might be partly responsible for
the weakening of the influence of distance that has been occurring
since World War II. This last hypothesis receives confirmation as
well. Finally, the paper examines the impact of internal distance
and remoteness on trade. Since both variables are country-specific,
this is done by studying their impact on the country fixed effects
themselves in the earlier estimates. Internal distance turns out
to have a far greater impact than remoteness—by an order of
10.
|
Sourafel Girma, Richard Kneller and Mauro Pis.
Do exporters have anything to learn from foreign multinationals?
|
International technology diffusion through FDI
has been examined mainly at macro or industry level whereas micro
studies have been concerned mostly with spillovers. Using recent
data on the UK manufacturing firms, this paper uncovers evidence
that acquisition FDI is an important channel of direct technology
transfer from foreign multinationals to domestic exporters. This
finding accords with the prediction of the internalisation theory
of FDI which postulates that multinational firms transfer a range
of intangible proprietary assets to their affiliates.
|
Elissaios Papyrakis and Reyer Gerlagh.Resource
abundance and economic growth in the United States
|
It is a common assumption that regions within the
same country converge to approximately the same steady-state income
levels. The so-called absolute convergence hypothesis focuses on
initial income levels to account for the variability in income growth
among regions. Empirical data seem to support the absolute convergence
hypothesis for US states, but the data also show that natural resource
abundance is a significant negative determinant of growth. We find
that natural resource abundance decreases investment, schooling,
openness, and R&D expenditure and increases corruption, and
we show that these effects can fully explain the negative effect
of natural resource abundance on growth.
|
Paul R. Bergin, Hyung-Cheol Shin and Ivan Tchakarov.Does
exchange rate variability matter for welfare? A quantitative investigation
of stabilization policies
|
This paper studies what degree of exchange rate
stabilization is optimal for several types of open economies. This
is accomplished through a quantitative evaluation of optimal monetary
policy rules in a two-country sticky-price model. First, a calibrated
benchmark model with incomplete asset markets supports past conclusions
from simpler models, emphasizing inflation stabilization rather
than exchange rate stabilization. It also highlights that the utility
gains from optimal stabilization policy are small. Second, while
an economy extended to include consumer habits implies greater sensitivity
by households to consumption variability, it has only minor effects
on the benchmark conclusions and benefits. Finally, these conclusions
are altered under an alternative environment where international
asset markets exhibit asymmetry in the form of “original sin.”
Such countries can benefit from policies that aggressively stabilize
the exchange rate, with utility gains larger than the previous cases.
|
|