TÍTULO: |
Explorations in Economic History
|
NÚMERO: |
Vol.44 No.2 April 2007
|
DIRECCIÓN ELECTRONICA: |
http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/journal/00144983
|
NOTAS: |
Este vínculo es el único para entrar a la base de datos Science Direct. Para ver el número de revista al que se hace referencia en este boletín, selecciónelo en el menú del lado izquierdo.
En este sitio usted encontrará la versión íntegra de los artículos en formato Acrobat (PDF).
|
|
|
ABSTRACTS |
Editorial Board
Page IFC
|
No tiene resumen
|
Howard Bodenhorn.Usury ceilings and bank lending behavior:
Evidence from nineteenth century New York
|
Few pieces of economic regulation are ubiquitous
as usury limits. Similarly, few economic principles are as widely
accepted as the belief that interference with freely contracted
prices leads to market distortions, and many studies of financial
markets find that usury limits negatively affect credit availability.
This study shows that when no regulatory authority monitors and
stands ready to punish violators of the usury limit when intermediaries
and borrowers form long-term relationships, banks and borrowers
regularly contract for interest rates in excess of the usury ceiling.
Time-series analysis reveals limited effects on credit availability
when market rates exceed the usury ceiling. Cross-sectional analysis
of individual loan contracts also shows that the positive effect
of a long-term relationship offsets the negative effect of the usury
limit on credit availability.
|
Jochen Streb, Jacek Wallusch and Shuxi Yin.Knowledge
spill-over from new to old industries: The case of German synthetic
dyes and textiles (1878–1913)
|
We construct a data set of long-lived German patents
of patent classes dyes (22) and dyeing (8) to measure the accumulation
path of technological knowledge with respect to dyeing textiles.
Using these data we show with a vector error correction model that
in the German Empire inter-industry knowledge spill-over between
the new chemical industry and the old textile industry created an
upward circle of “endogenous growth.” The increasing
demand for synthetic dyes of the prospering textile firms initiated
further research and development projects of the chemical firms
that led to new patents and via customer consulting and customer
training to additional economic benefits of the textile industry.
|
Solomos Solomou and Masao Shimazaki.Japanese
episodic long swings in economic growth
|
Prior to World War II Japanese economic growth
was characterised by episodic ‘long swings,’ low frequency
fluctuations in economic growth averaging about 20–25 years
in duration. At the aggregate level, these inter-period growth variations
dominated both shorter-term fluctuations and longer-term trend acceleration.
The paper describes the long swings of the Japanese economy and
re-evaluates conventional explanations.
|
William H. Phillips. Profitability and
factory-based cotton gin production in the antebellum south
|
Before 1820 Northern mechanics started factory-based
cotton gin manufacturing to compete with traditional Southern “ginwrights.”
Later, cotton gin production in factories was transferred to the
South. This paper estimates the profitability of cotton gin makers
in the antebellum industrial census. The Southern sector was more
profitable than that of the North, explaining the regional migration
of machine production resources. Besides transport cost protection,
Southern firms had a cost advantage in sales and service networks.
Specific factor investments in gin making limited further resource
flows from North to South after 1840. It also reduced the industry’s
impact on Southern economic development.
|
Michael J. Greenwood.Modeling the age
and age composition of late 19th century U.S. immigrants from Europe
|
Using panel data on 12 European source countries
that are followed for 26 years (1873–1898), this paper studies
age-specific emigration rates and the age composition of U.S. immigration.
Two age groups are the focus of attention, 15–40 and over
40. Emigration-rate models and compositional models that satisfy
adding-up conditions are estimated by the Hausman–Taylor Instrumental
Variable approach. Younger migrants responded more strongly to job
opportunities than to wage differentials, whereas older migrants
responded more strongly to wage differentials. Both age groups tended
to follow recent past migrants to the U.S. Relatively many younger
(and relatively fewer older) migrants came from countries with higher
percentages of their work forces in agriculture. Higher source-country
birthrates discouraged younger migrants, presumably by raising the
cost of family migration.
|
Daniel Gottlieb. Asymmetric information
in late 19th century cooperative insurance societies
|
Between 1880 and 1930, cooperative insurance was
the main source of illness, accident, and death insurance in the
United States, Canada, and England. This paper tests for asymmetric
information in cooperative insurance societies and examines how
their pricing policies affected the profile of members. We find
strong evidence that, unlike their modern substitutes, cooperative
societies were able to overcome the asymmetry of information. Furthermore,
as a consequence of non-actuarial pricing, our results suggest that
workers deferred their membership until they were about 40 years
old.
|
Giovanni Federico.Market integration
and market efficiency: The case of 19th century Italy
|
This paper examines market integration in Italy
in the 19th century, focusing on wheat. Wheat prices converged well
before political Unification (1859–1861) but the process halted
during the 1860s only to resume in the 1870s and 1880s. The first
wave of integration was caused mainly by improvements in market
efficiency while the second wave owed much to a reduction in transport
costs.
|
Daniel K. Benjamin and Christopher Thornberg.Organization
and incentives in the age of sail
|
The British Navy in the age of sail was the most
successful bureaucracy of its time. Its organization and incentive
structures differed importantly from contemporaneous private sailing
ventures, but closely resembled those of today’s large corporations.
To induce efficient effort, the navy used a hierarchical tournament,
in which sailors competed for higher pay that came with promotions
based on relative performance. Promotion probabilities, the option
value of future promotions, and the higher effort required of men
in higher ranks and on larger vessels, combined to yield a highly
skewed pay structure.
|
David S. Jacks. Populists versus theorists:
Futures markets and the volatility of prices
|
In this paper, the divergence between popular and
professional opinion on speculation in general and futures markets
in particular is explored. Along the way, a synopsis of prevailing
popular attitudes on futures markets is presented, and an outline
of a formal model of futures markets and its implications for commodity
price volatility are sketched. The heart of the analysis is drawn
from the historical record on the establishment and prohibition
of futures markets. Briefly, the results presented in this paper
strongly suggest that futures markets were associated with—and
most likely caused—lower commodity price volatility. The paper
concludes with a discussion of potential sources of popular antagonism
against futures markets.
|
Alexander J. Field. Erratum to “The
equipment hypothesis and US economic growth” [Explor. Econ.
Hist. 44 (2007) 43–58]
|
No tiene resumen
|
Table of Contents
Page OBC
|
No tiene resumen
|
|
TÍTULO: |
The Quarterly Review of Economics
and Finance
|
NÚMERO: |
Vo.47 No. 2 May 2007
|
DIRECCIÓN ELECTRONICA: |
http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/journal/10629769
|
NOTAS: |
Este vínculo es el único para entrar a la base de datos Science Direct. Para ver el número de revista al que se hace referencia en este boletín, selecciónelo en el menú del lado izquierdo.
En este sitio usted encontrará la versión íntegra de los artículos en formato Acrobat (PDF).
|
|
|
ABSTRACTS |
Editorial Board
Page iii
PDF (22 K)
|
No tiene resumen
|
A Letter from Editors
Pages 195-197
PDF (49 K)
|
No tiene resumen
|
John C. Alexander, Scott W. Barnhart and Stuart Rosenstein.
Do investor perceptions of corporate governance initiatives
affect firm value: The case of TIAA-CREF
|
We examine the valuation effect of the announcement
of TIAA-CREF's Corporate Governance Policy, an exogenous event fitting
McConnell's [McConnell, J. J. (2003). Outside directors. Financial
Review, 38, 25–31] description of a “controlled experiment”.
This event avoids the negative connotation associated with announcements
concerning specific firms. Abnormal returns are positively related
to the number of large block holders and the number of institutional
owners, indicating that the values of firms with weak governance
structures declined or the values of firms with desirable governance
structures increased. Also, the percentage of institutional ownership
and the number of institutional owners have a low correlation, indicating
that they are different dimensions of institutional ownership.
|
Subhash C. Sharma, Kevin Sylwester and Heru Margono.Decomposition
of total factor productivity growth in U.S. states
|
This paper applies the stochastic frontier production
model to the lower 48 U.S. states over the period 1977–2000
to decompose the sources of total factor productivity (TFP) growth
into technological progress, changes in technical efficiency, and
changes in economies of scale. We find that technological progress
comprises the majority of TFP growth but that differences in efficiency
change explain cross-state differences in TFP growth. TFP growth
was greater towards the end of the time period.
|
Mohamed Ihsan Ajwad and Quentin Wodon. Do
local Governments maximize access rates to public services across
areas?: A test based on marginal benefit incidence analysis
|
This paper investigates whether the poor (or those
who live in more densely populated areas) benefit more or less than
the non-poor (or those who live in less densely populated areas)
from an expansion in public services and whether this depends on
the type of service provided. Using data from Bolivia, we analyze
the allocation of education and basic infrastructure services across
jurisdictions. Results indicate that the marginal benefit incidence
is higher for the poor than for the non-poor in education, but lower
in the case of access to infrastructure services. A model is proposed
to suggest that the distribution of the observed marginal benefits
from an expansion in the public provision of services is consistent
with local Governments maximizing average access rates. This maximization
appears to occur without policymakers placing varying distributional
weights on the poor and rich in their implicit social welfare function.
|
Paul R. Zimmerman and Susan M.V. Flaherty.Location
monopolies and prison phone rates
|
Prisoners incarcerated in state correctional facilities
are often limited to making operator-assisted collect calls to their
families and associates. Prison phone services are supplied by a
single carrier who receives an exclusive service contract through
a procurement auction conducted by the state's Department of Corrections
(DOC). To win the auction, a firm must offer the highest “kickback”
or “site commission” to the DOC, which in turn is passed-on
to the recipients of prison collect calls – typically family
members – in the form of higher rates. The recipients have
little choice but to pay these inflated rates since there is no
other alternative for maintaining contact with their incarcerated
loved one. Some states have attempted to alleviate the burden of
excessive prison collect call rates by changing the methodology
used to asses site commissions. The purpose of this study is to
empirically evaluate the efficacy of these reforms. The empirical
results suggest that the cost of receiving IntraLATA prison collect
calls is approximately 41% higher in those states that impose site
commissions based as a percentage of the carriers’ ex post
revenues relative to those states that impose fixed commissions
ex ante. The results are shown to be highly robust with respect
to model specification, estimation technique, and control for outliers.
|
David Y. Chen.Effects of monetary policy
on the twin deficits
|
This study uses a three-equation dynamic linear
system to show the positive relationship between federal budget
deficits and the 5-year Treasury bond rate and between the twin
deficits in the U.S. during 1975:01 through 2004:12. An optimal
efficient rule equation suggests that a one percentage point increase
in bond rate explains a 22% budget deficit variations. A one index
point change in nominal exchange rate correlates to a 78% variation
in budget deficits. When real exchange rate is adopted in the system,
the corresponding percentages become 14 and 86, respectively, showing
the fading influence of T-bond rate and the increasing strength
of exchange rate.
|
Information transmission and spillover
in currency markets: A generalized variance decomposition analysis
|
The unique characteristics of newly public firms
may motivate acquisitions and cause a unique market perception and
performance following these acquisitions. For a sample of more than
400 acquisitions that were made within a year of the IPO, we find
that newly public firms experience favorable valuation effects following
announcements of their acquisitions. Firms are more likely to finance
using stock and the valuation effects are less favorable during
the Internet bubble and when venture capitalists are present. Finally,
long-term performance following the acquisitions is not different
than newly public firms that do not make acquisitions, suggesting
that the expected benefits at the time of the announcement do not
materialize.
|
Joan Wiggenhorn, Kimberly C. Gleason and Jeff Madura.
Going public to pursue acquisitions
|
The unique characteristics of newly public firms
may motivate acquisitions and cause a unique market perception and
performance following these acquisitions. For a sample of more than
400 acquisitions that were made within a year of the IPO, we find
that newly public firms experience favorable valuation effects following
announcements of their acquisitions. Firms are more likely to finance
using stock and the valuation effects are less favorable during
the Internet bubble and when venture capitalists are present. Finally,
long-term performance following the acquisitions is not different
than newly public firms that do not make acquisitions, suggesting
that the expected benefits at the time of the announcement do not
materialize.
|
Hassan Shirvani and Barry Wilbratte. The
permanent-transitory decomposition of the stock markets of the G7
countries: A multivariate approach
|
This paper tests for the presence of common stochastic
trends and cycles in the stock prices of the G7 countries. It further
uses the existing common trends and cycles to provide a parsimonious
decomposition of the stock prices into their permanent and transitory
components, using the method of (Proetti, T. (1997). Short-run dynamics
in cointegrated systems. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics,
59, 405–422) and (Hecq, A., Palm, F.C., & Urbain, P. (2000).
Permanent-transitory decomposition in VAR models with cointegration
and common cycles. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics,
62.4, 511–532). Finally, we offer some tentative evidence
on the determinants of the permanent and transitory components of
the G7 stock prices. Our evidence explains the trends in terms of
fundamentals and cycles in terms of psychological factors, with
interesting possible implications for international portfolio management.
|
Chunrong Ai, Arjun Chatrath and Frank Song.A
semiparametric estimation of the optimal hedge ratio
|
Standard static hedging models employing futures
contracts yield poor results for most commodities, especially when
compared with the evidence for financial instruments such as stock
indexes and currencies. Moreover, the efforts in the dynamic hedging
of commodity prices via GARCH models have found limited success.
In this paper, we propose an alternate approach for constructing
the ‘optimal’ hedge ratio. The approach differs from
previous methods in two respects. First, we incorporate controls
for seasonals, time to maturity, inventories, and futures term-structure
in the construction of hedge ratio. Second, we adopt a partially
linear functional form for the hedge ratio. Employing data from
the U.S. markets for corn, cotton, and soybeans, we find that our
method substantially outperforms the static, semi-dynamic, and GARCH
models.
|
|